Reproduced with permission from
the United Nations Research Institute for Social
Development
|
Authoritarian
Rule and Democracy in Africa: A Theoretical Discourse
|
|
2. Stages in the
Struggles for Democracy In this section I
examine more concretely the interplay of authoritarian and democratic rule. Of the six
models outlined only B, C, D and perhaps E approximate to concrete African experiences.
This excludes the South African case, whose forms of accumulation are similar to those of
model A, but whose apartheid system has prevented the development of a national democratic
system. In discussing the stages in the struggles for democracy, I focus mainly on C and
D. Only a few countries have practiced model B, the clientelist type of democracy. I am,
at this stage, mainly concerned with general historical patterns. No attempt is made to
focus on any particular country. Needless to add that such broad historical surveys tend
to simplify and, in some cases, gloss over unique characteristics.
The struggle for democracy in Africa has a complex and
tortuous history. Democratization triumphed at certain historical conjunctures, but it was
blocked and suppressed in other phases. I identify three stages in the contemporary
struggles for democracy: the decolonization period of guided democratization; the
post-colonial period of state capitalist expansion and authoritarian rule; and the period
of economic crisis which is currently generating pressures for re-democratization. The
character of the democratic project differs in each period, being structurally related to
the underlying forms of accumulation, the level of development of the corresponding civil
societies, and the nature of the social contracts and public welfare. |
|
2.1
Decolonization and guided democratization Decolonization
in much of Africa occurred within the context of guided democratization. After much
prevarication, the colonial authorities were forced to embrace democracy as a strategy for
maintaining core residual interests. It was envisaged that plural forms of politics would
sharpen local differences and dilute the militancy of the anti-colonial opposition.
Furthermore, the values of individual self-interest were expected to permeate the social
milieu of the leading nationalists. The emerging élites, on the other hand, saw democracy
as a strategy to end their subordinate positions in the colonial economy. Educated
professionals wanted greater access to state resources and an improved standard of living
that would reflect their training and perceived social status. Those in the commercial
sector were anxious to break the monopolistic power of the colonial banks and trading
companies.
Subordinate groups also pushed through their own demands.
Workers wanted to have independent unions to negotiate freely with employers realistic
wages and benefits that would reflect the post-war cost of living. Peasants and artisans
were concerned about improved prices for their products; and students wanted to expand the
frontiers of African education and political power. Democratization provided an
institutional framework for reconciling the conflicting interests thrown up by the
authoritarian colonial economy. It checked the absolutism of colonial rule by opening up
space for popular participation in government and the rise of independent organizations.
But the authoritarian character of the colonial economy
prevented the growth of liberal democracy. The colonial state forcibly restructured
pre-existing economies and subsequently regulated peasant production through monopolistic
trading companies and marketing boards. The trading monopolies and the state failed to
transform the petty commodity sector and rural society in general. There was also hardly
any major form of urban industrialization. Underdevelopment and dependency theory has
adequately described the enclave dynamics and rural-urban socio-economic disarticulation
that informed this type of development. What is more, public welfare occupied very low
priority in the governance of those societies as very conservative fiscal and monetary
policies were pursued. Public welfare did not become a major issue in state policy until
the structures of decolonization were put in place in the 1940s.2 Colonial rule was maintained through the use of force and the
clientelist structures of indirect rule.
Democratization and decolonization took place against the
background of a poorly developed civil society. Intense struggles had to be waged over the
question of making the modern élites and their political parties the vanguard and
pathways to self-government, rather than the traditional structures of authority which
were dominated by the state (Nordman, 1979).
The original colonial agenda was subsequently defeated.
The struggle for democracy and self-rule was conducted mainly through the medium of
urban-based political parties, communal associations and workers unions. Although a class
structure was already discernible, those who participated in the nationalist struggles did
so mainly as individuals rather than as representatives of corporate organizations. This
was the case whether the actors were journalists, academics, doctors, students, farmers,
artisans or market women. Their respective organizations, where they existed, were poorly
developed to advance any viable corporate strategy. Individuals tended to act almost
unilaterally on behalf of their social groups. The underdevelopment of civil organizations
allowed the educated élites to determine the direction of decolonization. The élites
were the only group with the capacity to pull the disparate social forces together and
articulate national development strategies.
But democratization also strengthened the alliance between
the emerging élites and the colonial authorities. This facilitated the growth of a
nascent local bourgeoisie. It gave the anti-colonial alliance a decidedly class character
and blunted the popular orientation of the democratic project. Rather than democratize the
colonial economy, the nationalist élites ruled through the state monopolies and the
colonial patronage networks to consolidate and expand their economic and political power.
In Nigeria, for instance, the regionalization of the marketing boards in the run up to
independence led to the transfer of accumulated peasant surpluses into the hands of
competing politicians and business groups. Public probes showed how these resources were
plundered by the emerging dominant power élite (Osoba, 1978). Decolonization did not
fully establish democratic rule, even though the period stands out as a major landmark in
democratic experiments in Africa. Representative governments were introduced in controlled
stages (Collier, 1982); the right to free expression and association was coloured with
proscriptions, the banning of radical literature and the arrest of activists considered to
be too militant for the transition process. |
|
2.2 State
capitalist expansion and authoritarian rule The
first decade and a half of independence was remarkable for the emergence of a model of
accumulation that questioned the limited advances in democratization. Elaborate strategies
were formulated by the new rulers, donor agencies and the World Bank to accelerate the
pace of development. The basic model was influenced by the dominant Keynesian-oriented
paradigm in development economics, which stressed the need for state intervention to
correct market failures and stimulate the process of industrialization (Taylor and
Shapiro, 1990). The state would use the proceeds of peasant surplus and rents from
extractive industries to finance régimes of import-substitution industrialization. Where
such surpluses were not enough, donor agencies and private foreign capital would provide
the extra finance. The state was to offer a package of incentives to foreign enterprises,
subsidize the growth of local capital and transform the petty commodity sector. Social
expenditure projects were to be launched to provide basic infrastructure for development,
and to sustain the loyalty of the subordinate groups of the anti-colonial alliance. The
fledgling business groups would ultimately appropriate a large chunk of the resources of
such projects for their own development.
The model registered some interesting rates of growth in a
number of African countries, particularly Cameroon, Côte d'Ivoire, Gabon, Kenya, Malawi,
and Nigeria, prompting many Marxists and liberal development economists to question the
static assumptions and predictions of underdevelopment theory. As Mkandawire notes, "...Between
1960 and 1975...Africa's industry (which) grew at the annual rate of 7.5 per
cent...compared favourably with the 7.8 per cent for Latin America (and the) 7.5 per cent
for South-East Asia" (Mkandawire, 1988a: 31). The GDP growth rates for the period
1965-1973 was 6.1 per cent (World Bank, 1989). In most countries, the state became the
major source of investment and national employment. State expenditure in schools, health,
public services and food supplies grew exponentially. In 1972, just a year before the
first world oil price shocks, central government expenditure for 21 sub-Saharan African
countries for which data are available was 21.1 per cent of the gross national products3 (World Bank, 1989). Although there were attempts in a number of
countries to promote integrated rural development, the overall development strategy
worsened the rural-urban terms of trade and led to flights of rural populations into urban
centres. Economic growth intensified class differentiation and encouraged the growth of
institutional forms of social organization with mandates from members to bargain for the
expanding public resources. The era of rent-seeking forms of state capitalism had arrived.
What was the social and political basis of this model of
accumulation? In his seminal work of 1973, O'Donnell challenged one of the central
hypotheses of liberal democratic theory that associates rapid economic development with
political democracy. In the Latin American context of the 1960s and 1970s, high rates of
growth and modernization produced, instead, what O'Donnell called "bureaucratic-authoritarianism"
(O'Donnell, 1973). Indeed, Brazil's military rulers relied on their country's record of
high growth rates to legitimize their authoritarian rule for much of that period (Martins,
1986).
Taking into account Africa's lower levels of
industrialization and bureaucratic development, it seems to me that O'Donnell's
proposition captures some aspects of the African experience of the same period. Democracy
was seen by the new African rulers and emerging local entrepreneurs as obstructive of both
corporate and private accumulation. It encouraged demands for redistribution as opposed to
production, and forced rulers and entrepreneurs to be accountable to the wider populace
for the way they handled public resources; it was also felt that democracy would
facilitate ethnic polarization at the expense of national unity. Military and one-party
dictatorships were defended as necessary political arrangements for nation building and
economic development. In the context of Africa's changing societies, democracy was seen as
a source of political instability (Huntington, 1968; Mamdani, Mkandawire and
Wamba-dia-Wamba, 1988; Anyang' Nyong'o, 1988b).
Several ideologies, ranging from African socialism and
humanism to negritude and authenticity, were propagated by the new rulers to control
dissent and project African societies as homogeneous. The democratic impulse of the
decolonization period had taught the emergent social groups the power of collective action
in the politics of resource allocation. The logical growth of civil society that the
expansion of unions, professional associations and interest group organizations created
was seen by the dominant groups and state authorities as a threat to economic development
and private accumulation.
Various strategies were employed to regulate the
activities of the social groups. One-party régimes with "socialist orientations"
simply co-opted some of the popular organizations into the party structures and floated
alternative organizations at various levels of society to check the development of new
autonomous organizations. Such practices were common in Benin, the Congo, Ghana under
Nkrumah, Guinea under Sekou Toure, and Tanzania. Other less ideological one-party states
imposed restrictions on the activities of unions and associations, co-opted the leadership
of popular organizations into policy-making institutions, and strengthened patron-client
relations with traditional authority. Cameroon, Côte d'Ivoire, Kenya, Malawi, Senegal
(before the democratic reforms) and Sierra Leone fall under this category. Military
régimes such as those of Mali, Niger, Nigeria, Togo and Zaire tended to follow the
practices of the latter, although some, like Nigeria, were relatively less successful in
controlling dissent and co-opting popular organizations. The relative openness of
political life that flourished under decolonization was severely curtailed in most
countries.
Authoritarianism did not however destroy the social
contract that underpinned the nationalist struggles. Indeed, the legitimacy of
authoritarian rule rested on the ability and willingness of the political authorities to
promote public welfare. Such an ability depended on the sustainability of economic growth.
The social contract that provided such legitimacy was unabashedly top-down. Popular
struggles against these repressive arrangements were initiated and sustained in a number
of countries (Anyang' Nyong'o, 1988a), but the balance was unmistakably in favour of
generalized authoritarian rule. |
|
|
2.3 Economic
crisis and pressures for re-democratization The
authoritarian model based its legitimacy on continued accumulation, positive rates of
growth and the provision of public welfare. But African societies entered a stage of
profound crisis in the late 1970s/early 1980s as a result of the recession in the world
market and the structural problems of the state capitalist model of development. Where as
only 10 out of 34 sub-Saharan African countries experienced negative per capita GDP growth
rates between 1965 and 1980, only nine registered any per capita GDP growth rate between
1980 and 1987 (Helleiner, 1990; World Bank, 1989). Average GDP growth rates for all SSA
countries fell from 6.1 per cent in 1965-73 to -1.3 per cent in 1987. Agriculture,
industry and services registered marked declines in rates of growth, with industry falling
from 13.5 per cent in 1965-73 to -1.2 per cent in 1980-87. The same poor record is
demonstrated in export volume and terms of trade. The total debt of SSA countries jumped
from US $21.1 billion in 1976 to US $137.8 billion in 1987. The ratio of
external debt to GDP increased from 45.2 per cent in 1981 to 66.1 per cent in 1986 (IMF,
1988; Taylor, 1989). Table 3 highlights some of the negative trends in economic
performance.
Table 3 |
GDP growth rates,
sector growth rates,
growth of export volume and terms of trade (1965-1987) |
|
1965-1973 |
1973-1980 |
1980-1985 |
1986 |
1987 |
GDP growth rates |
6.1 |
3.2 |
-0.5 |
3.2 |
-1.3 |
Sector growth rates |
Agriculture |
2.4 |
0.3 |
1.2 (1980-1987) |
Industry |
13.5 |
4.7 |
-1.2 (1980-1987) |
Services |
4.1 |
3.6 |
1.5 (1980-1987) |
Growth of export volume |
15.1 |
0.2 |
-3.3 |
1.1 |
-3.3 |
Manufactures |
7.6 |
5.6 |
4.4 |
1.3 |
4.8 |
Primary goods |
15.4 |
-0.0 |
-3.7 |
1.1 |
-3.5 |
Terms of trade |
-8.5 |
5.0 |
-2.3 |
-23.2 |
3.3 |
The figures for export volumes in 1987 are estimates. Source:
World Bank, World Development Report, 1989.
The crisis narrowed urban-rural terms of trade and
differentials in social livelihood (Jamal and Weeks, 1988). This did not, however,
strengthen rural welfare and urban-rural integration as most economies experienced sharp
declines in their major macro-economic and social indicators. It was mainly a question of
lowering urban living standards without necessarily raising those of the rural
communities. Available data for 11 African countries in Table 4 show the effects of the
crisis on public expenditure on education and health. The percentage of total expenditure
on education declined in seven countries, and on health it declined in nine, even though
only four countries cut their overall budget deficits as a percentage of their gross
national product. Stewart reckoned that real government expenditure per head fell in 55
per cent of African countries between 1980 and 1984 (Stewart, 1987). The situation would
have deteriorated in most countries in the mid-to-late 1980s.
Table 4 |
Central government
expenditure in selected countries |
|
Percentage of total
expenditure
Education Health |
Total expenditure
(% of GNP) |
Overall surplus/
deficit (% of GNP) |
|
1972 |
1987 |
1972 |
1987 |
1972 |
1987 |
1972 |
1987 |
Botswana |
10.0 |
18.4 |
6.0 |
5.9 |
33.7 |
47.5 |
-23.8 |
28.2 |
Burkina Faso |
20.6
|
19.0
|
8.2
|
5.8
|
11.1
|
16.3
|
0.3
|
1. 6
|
Ghana |
20.1 |
23.9 |
6.3 |
8.3 |
19.5 |
14.1 |
-5.8 |
0.6 |
Kenya |
21.9 |
23.1 |
7.9 |
6.6 |
21.0 |
25.0 |
-3.9 |
-4.6 |
Liberia |
15.2 |
16.2 |
9.8 |
7.1 |
16.7 |
24.8 |
1.1 |
-7.9 |
Lesotho |
22.4 |
15.5 |
7.4 |
6.9 |
14.5 |
24.3 |
3.5 |
-2.6 |
Malawi |
15.8 |
10.8 |
5.5 |
7.1 |
22.1 |
35.1 |
-6.2 |
-10.3 |
Nigeria |
4.5 |
2.8 |
3.6 |
0.8 |
8.3 |
27.7 |
-0.7 |
-10.3 |
Tanzania |
17.3 |
8.3 |
7.2 |
5.7 |
19.7 |
20.9 |
-5.0 |
-4.9 |
Uganda |
15.3 |
15.0 |
5.3 |
2.4 |
21.8 |
15.0 |
-8.1 |
-4.4 |
Zambia |
19.0 |
8.3 |
7.4 |
4.7 |
34.0 |
40.3 |
-13.8 |
-15.8 |
Source: World Bank, World Development Report,
1989.
Radical reform programmes, influenced or initiated by the
IMF and the World Bank, have been introduced to check the unprecedented economic decline.
The reforms aim to restructure economic relations in the production and consumption of
commodities. The restructuring primarily affects incomes, public welfare and prices, which
in turn affect the configurations of power. The aim is to eliminate distortions associated
with the expansion of the post-colonial state by giving the market a relatively freer hand
in the allocation of resources. These distortions are to be found in the exchange rates,
tariff régimes, the organization of parastatals, interest rates and public expenditure.
It is a major challenge to the state capitalist model of macro-economic management and the
values and group interests that have been nurtured around it.
Rolling back the state does not only affect popular
classes and groups, it also affects ruling class forces. Large-scale public expenditure,
as we have seen, was not just a strategy for protecting the poor, it was also an avenue
for dominant groups to siphon off public resources. The same applies to over-valued
exchange rates, discriminatory tariffs, the establishment of parastatals and low interest
rates, all of which played crucial roles in the accumulation of capital, class formation
and the subsidy of the consumption habits of the rich and powerful. Structural adjustment
poses, therefore, problems for all classes and groups. In fact, the economic reforms seek
to purify the business groups, provide a new type of legitimacy for their class rule and
consolidate their positions in the wider political economy. Such a project is to be
achieved at the expense of the nationalist coalition and social contract that underpinned
the state capitalist model of development.
Market reformers seek to reconstitute the relationship
between foreign and local capital (liberalization strengthens the hands of the former),
restructure agrarian relations to support export agriculture and hold back the urban
classes of workers, sections of middle class professionals and the urban poor. It is not
surprising that the strongest opponents of the reforms are a new coalition of middle class
professionals, industrial unions, student organizations and the urban dispossessed.
Pressures from such coalitions have led to a number of riots in Algeria, Benin, Egypt,
Ghana, Liberia, Nigeria, Sierra Leone, Sudan, Tunisia and Zambia. Given the benefits that
are likely to accrue to rural communities because of the price reforms and devaluation,
some governments have tried to mobilize the rural groups to counter the political weight
of the organized urban sector (Gyimah-Boadi, 1989), but the response so far has been
lukewarm. Peasants remain sceptical of crucial aspects of the reforms such as fluctuations
in prices, the withdrawal of subsidies from farm inputs, escalating costs of production,
and general levels of inflation that affect their consumption of traded goods.
Struggles to protect living standards in the context of
crisis and adjustment tend to take on a democratic character. Organized groups demand the
institutionalization of collective bargaining, the independence of unions and associations
and respect for the rule of law and civil liberties. These are considered to be critical
for holding employers and state authorities accountable for their economic policies.
Social movements are emboldened by the collapse of the post-colonial social contract and
growth rates to press for the reconstitution of the relationship between the state and
civil society. Repressive policies to support the implementation of adjustment programmes
have not been effective in controlling dissent. Military and one-party forms of rule have
come under increasing opposition from organized groups and individuals. Co-opted unions
and associations agitate for organizational autonomy from established parties and
governments to defend the declining welfare of their members (the Congo, Zambia). Current
developments seem to contradict the predictions of neo-liberal theory which expects the
business class to play a leading role in democratization (Diamond, 1988). The market
reforms, it is argued, will liberate the enterprising potentials of the business groups
and encourage them to opt for more democratic modes of government.
Although some business groups and organizations have sided
with the popular groups in demanding the reintroduction of multi-party rule in such
countries as Benin, Kenya, and Zambia, most of the demonstrations for democracy have been
organized by opposition groups and parties with traditional sympathies for the aspirations
of the poor. Even those who have joined the pro-democracy movement from the top have done
so in the context of advancing the general interests of the populace and advocating for
development programmes that would protect the poor and vulnerable sections of society.
Contrary to neo-liberal formulations, democratization is seen by the majority of dissident
groups as an instrument for obstructing structural adjustment and protecting some of the
gains in public welfare and living standards threatened by the reforms. A number of
military and one-party régimes have come under considerable pressure to initiate
programmes for transitions to multi-party rule. Indeed, partly encouraged by the
experiences in Eastern Europe, there has been an intense debate for multi-party democracy
in most African countries. The link between alternative strategies of development and
democracy has featured in most of these debates. Some governments, such as Benin, Côte d'Ivoire,
Gabon, Mozambique, Zaire and Zambia, have even been forced to initiate plans for
transitions to multi-party rule. Other régimes like those of Kenya and Sierra Leone have
not conceded much ground to the opposition groups. Similarly, struggles in the existing
democracies of the Gambia, Senegal and Zimbabwe have focused on the question of curtailing
the post-colonial dominance of the ruling parties and extending the social content of
democracy (Bathily, 1989; Moyo, 1989).
The next section examines the politics of transition from
authoritarian military rule to democracy. Issues relating to democratization are different
from those of sustainable democracy. Sustainability, as we have seen, deals with a complex
of economic, social and political factors which may profoundly influence the orientation
and character of democratization. Democratization is, however, explicitly political. It
concerns the processes of liberalization in the key areas of political life, viz. the
demilitarization of the state apparatus; the strengthening of civil society and its
institutions; and the democratization of the rules of economic and political competition.
The nature of the links between civil and political society occupies a central position in
the dynamics and regulation of democratization. I discuss these issues against the
background of the Nigerian experience.
2 Riots in the West Indies, Mauritius and the Gold Coast culminated in the
decision by the British government to review the Colonial Development Act of 1929. The
Watson Report on the riots set the stage for the Colonial Development and Welfare Act of
1945. See Parliamentary Command Papers 6174 and 6175 (UK) 1940.
3 Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Chad, Ethiopia, Gabon, Ghana, Kenya, Lesotho,
Madagascar, Malawi, Nigeria, Rwanda, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Somalia, Sudan, Tanzania,
Uganda, Zaire, Zambia.
|
Contents Previous Next |
|
|